Identification of ATSMs
Oh, Hyunzi. (email: wisdom302@naver.com)
Korea University, Graduate School of Economics.
Main References
Here, we address the problem of identification of the factors
Consider a Affine Term Structure Models > ^24c2e6Affine Term Structure Models > Definition 5 (Gaussian ATSM) given as
Remark that the time
An invariant affine transformation of the factors
Note that under
Without any restrictions, we are not able to figure out whether the yields were generated from the original GASTM model, or from the transformed model. In such situation, we call that the model is underidentified.
Note that under ^c86440Definition 1 (invariant affine transformation), the new parameters can be driven as follows:
Our goal is to identify the model against invariant affine transformations, by imposing restrictions on the model parameters so that there are only one set of factors that generate the yields and simultaneously satisfy such restrictions.
This means, for
In general, the affine term structure models are identified in two steps:
This model is first introduced in Dai and Singleton (2000), which imposes restrictions on the physical factor dynamics. Instead, we look into Singleton (2006), which is an equivalent version of the model with the restrictions on the risk-neutral dynamics, which restrictions are consistent with the JSZ ModelJSZ Model and AFNS modelAFNS model.
Consider a Gaussian ATSMGaussian ATSM stated as
Note that we only state the short rate and risk-neutral dynamics, since the physical factor dynamics are left unrestricted. Also, remark that Hamilton and Wu (2012) pointed out that without the third restrictions, the model is unidentified.
If the risk-neutral factor dynamics include a unit root, then we may impose restrictions on the physical factor dynamics instead, i.e.
However, if both risk-neutral and physical dynamics contain unit roots, then we must impose additional zero restrictions on
Another problem of ^026429Definition 2 (Dai-Singleton model) is that it does not encompass ATSM where
Here, we look JSZ model introduced in Joslin, Singleton, and Zhu (2011) that offers a seminal identification scheme for gaussian ATSMs.
Consider a Gaussian ATSMGaussian ATSM stated as
The JSZ model imposes the identification restrictions of
From Proof of Canonical JSZ modelProof of Canonical JSZ model, the JSZ modelJSZ model is observationally equivalent to an ATSM of
Below, we continue to work using this simpler model with the canonical factors
One of the contribution of the JSZ modelJSZ model is that it allows us to derive an observationally equivalent model with the observable factors.
Suppose the followings:
Thus we have
For simplicity, suppose that
Here, we choose
An alternative approach is to assume that some yields are perfectly priced, while the others are observed with error. Denote the yields under the first case as
While this approach is more restrictive than the 1) Using Principle Components1) Using Principle Components, it allows the case of non-stationary yields, adding more generality compared to the previous approach.
Whether 1) Using Principle Components1) Using Principle Components or 2) Using Perfectly Priced Yields2) Using Perfectly Priced Yields, we obtain
Then, an observantly equivalent Gaussian ASTM with factors
The arbitrage-free Nelson-Siegel (AFNS) model, presented by Christensen, Diebold, and Rudebusch (2011) and adapted for a discrete time by Niu and Zeng (2012), is a special case of the JSZ ModelJSZ Model.
While Dynamic Nelson-Siegel ModelDynamic Nelson-Siegel Model fits the yield curve very well, its main shortcoming is that it is an empirical model that does not impose the No-Arbitrage ConditionNo-Arbitrage Condition. Thus Nelson-Siegel model allows for arbitrage opportunities to arise, which brings up the need for an theoretically consistent model.
Consider a Gaussian ATSMGaussian ATSM stated as
Note that we do not impose any restrictions on the physical dynamics.
Thus, the short-rate and risk-neutral factor dynamics of AFNS model are given as
Under the restriction given in ^6231feDefinition 4 (AFNS model), we have the bond yields satisfying Dynamic Nelson-Siegel Model > ^0a7421Dynamic Nelson-Siegel Model > Proposition 1 (Nelson-Siegel restriction), i.e.
Proof.Note that by Affine Term Structure Models > ^beb7fdAffine Term Structure Models > Proposition 6 (Ricatti equation for ATSM), the prices and the yields of the bonds in Gaussian ASTM model are given as
Here, unlike the original Dynamic Nelson-Siegel ModelDynamic Nelson-Siegel Model, ^6231feDefinition 4 (AFNS model) contains the intercept term
Compared to the previous models, the AFNS model assume from the outset